Recession (economics): Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
m (Text replacement - "market" to "market (economics)")
 
(12 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 3: Line 3:


==Terminology==
==Terminology==
The terms '''recession''' and depression are used colloqually to describe any deep or persistant decline in economic activity, (and sometimes to a persistant reduction in the rate of growth of ouput). More precise definitions have been adopted the statistics authorities. In the United States the National Bureau of Economic Research defines a recession as  
The terms '''recession''' and depression are used colloquially to describe any deep or persistent decline in economic activity, (and sometimes to a persistent reduction in the rate of growth of ouput). More precise definitions have been adopted the statistics authorities. In the United States the National Bureau of Economic Research defines a recession as  
:''a significant decline in economic activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, and wholesale retail sales''<ref>[http://faq.bea.gov/cgi-bin/bea.cfg/php/enduser/std_adp.php?p_faqid=485&p_created=1206966790&p_sid=-OCpNEgj&p_accessibility=0&p_redirect=&p_lva=&p_sp=cF9zcmNoPSZwX3NvcnRfYnk9JnBfZ3JpZHNvcnQ9JnBfcm93X2NudD0zODMsMzgzJnBfcHJvZHM9JnBfY2F0cz0mcF9wdj0mcF9jdj0mcF9zZWFyY2hfdHlwZT1hbnN3ZXJzLnNlYXJjaF9ubCZwX3BhZ2U9MQ**&p_li=&p_topview=1 ''Recession: how is that defined?'', Bureau of Economics, US Department of Commerce]</ref><ref>[http://www.clevelandfed.org/research/trends/2008/1108/01ecoact.cfm For a further explanation and some examples  see ''What Is a Recession And Are We In One? Federal Reserve Bank  of Cleveland October 2008]</ref><br>
:''a significant decline in economic activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, and wholesale retail sales''<ref>[http://faq.bea.gov/cgi-bin/bea.cfg/php/enduser/std_adp.php?p_faqid=485&p_created=1206966790&p_sid=-OCpNEgj&p_accessibility=0&p_redirect=&p_lva=&p_sp=cF9zcmNoPSZwX3NvcnRfYnk9JnBfZ3JpZHNvcnQ9JnBfcm93X2NudD0zODMsMzgzJnBfcHJvZHM9JnBfY2F0cz0mcF9wdj0mcF9jdj0mcF9zZWFyY2hfdHlwZT1hbnN3ZXJzLnNlYXJjaF9ubCZwX3BhZ2U9MQ**&p_li=&p_topview=1 ''Recession: how is that defined?'', Bureau of Economics, US Department of Commerce]</ref><ref>[http://www.clevelandfed.org/research/trends/2008/1108/01ecoact.cfm For a further explanation and some examples  see ''What Is a Recession And Are We In One? Federal Reserve Bank  of Cleveland October 2008]</ref><br>
Other  authorities have not adopted a formal definition of recession but most commentators and analysts use<br>
Other  authorities have not adopted a formal definition of recession but most commentators and analysts use<br>
:'' a period of of negative growth of real (inflation-adjusted GDP lasting for at least two quarters]]''<ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2009/03/basics.htm  Stijn Claessens and M. Ayhan Kose: ''What Is a Recession?'', International Monetary Fund, March 2009]</ref>.<br>
:'' a period of of negative growth of real (inflation-adjusted) GDP lasting for at least two quarters''<ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2009/03/basics.htm  Stijn Claessens and M. Ayhan Kose: ''What Is a Recession?'', International Monetary Fund, March 2009]</ref>.<br>
The term [[balance sheet recession]] has been applied to a reduction in bank lending or consumer spending following the bursting of an [[asset price bubble]]. The term [[double-dip recession]] refers to a second fall in economic growth following an aborted recovery from a recession, such as occurred in the 1937-39 phase of the [[Great Depression]]. The terms [[downturn]], and "trough" are used to denote the onset of negative growth, and the point at which positive growth resumes.
The term [[double-dip recession]] refers to a second fall in economic growth following an aborted recovery from a recession, such as occurred in the 1937-39 phase of the [[Great Depression]]. The terms [[downturn (economic)|downturn]], and "trough" are used to denote the onset of negative growth, and the point at which positive growth resumes.


Before 1930, what are now termed recessions were referred to as "depressions". That term is nowadays  reserved for exceptionally severe or prolonged recessions.  Again there is no formal definition, but it has been suggested that  the term be applied to a decline in real GDP that exceeds 10%, or one that lasts more than three years<ref>[http://www.economist.com/finance/economicsfocus/displaystory.cfm?story_id=12852043 ''Diagnosing depression'', The Economist, Dec 30th 2008 ]</ref>.
Before 1930, what are now termed recessions were referred to as "depressions". That term is nowadays  reserved for exceptionally severe or prolonged recessions.  Again there is no formal definition, but it has been suggested that  the term be applied to a decline in real GDP that exceeds 10%, or one that lasts more than three years<ref>[http://www.economist.com/finance/economicsfocus/displaystory.cfm?story_id=12852043 ''Diagnosing depression'', The Economist, Dec 30th 2008 ]</ref>.


==How recessions start==
==The causes of recessions==
Recessions have  been triggered by events that have prompted firms and consumers to cut back their spending plans (termed  economic [[shock (economics)|shocks]]). The terms [[endogenous (economics)|endogenous]] and [[exogenous (economics)|exogenous]] are applied to shocks coming from within and outside the economy, and a distinction is usually drawn between changes of demand and changes of supply.  Exogenous [[demand shock]]s have included sudden falls in demand for exports, and endogenous demand shocks have included tax increases and [[credit crunch|credit crunches]].   [[Supply shock]]s, such as commodity price increases, have usually been  exogenous. Perceptions of shocks have been influenced by forecasts, rumours and [[herding (economics)|herding]] behaviour, as well as from factual reports and experiences. Global shocks (such as the [[crash of 2008]]) have arisen from the [[tight coupling|tighly coupled]] character of modern  [[financial system]]s, and  there have been many instances of the [[International economics#International financial stability|international contagion]] of domestic  shocks.
The causation of recessions is a topic of continuing controversy among economists, and is at the heart of the study of [[macroeconomics]], but there is general agreement concerning some of  their common characteristics. By common consent a recession is generally triggered by a failure of the [[market (economics)|market]] mechanisms that normally keep supply in line with demand. The result is a deficiency of demand, meaning that suppliers are unable to sell their output - and that, in particular, many people find themselves unable to get [[employment]] (a simple explanation of its occurrence is provided Richard Sweeney's [[/Tutorials#The baby-sitting crisis - an analogy|baby-sitting analogy]]). The breakdown of the market mechanism is often triggered by an economic "shock" that reduces consumer confidence.  


==What happens in a recession==
Recessions have commonly been brought about by sudden increases of commodity prices, or by  credit shortages resulting from financial crises. As a result, consumers and firms are prompted (or forced) to cut back on their spending. The fall in  spending  then prompts  suppliers to run down their stocks, which depresses activity among their suppliers and causes a further fall in aggregate demand. Previously employed resources of capital and labour fall out of use and a growing  [[output gap]] develops between actual and potential output (which is reflected in a gap between the growth rate of GDP and its former trend) and there is an increase in [[unemployment]]. A recovery normally follows as prices  fall in response to the reduction in demand, and as benefit payments and other social security payments  rise. As  consumer demand recovers, re-stocking by suppliers  tends to speed the recovery in economic activity.  (According to the "Zarnowitz rule", the steeper  the initial downturn in activity, the more rapid will be the subsequent upturn<ref>Victor Zarnowitz: ''What is a Business Cycle?'', NBER Working Paper No. W3863, National Bureau of Economic Research, October 1991</ref> (but that rule may not hold for balance sheet recessions).
There is an unsettled controversy concerning the mechanism of recessions, but they are known to have a number of common features.  
 
The running down of manufacturers' stocks hastens the decline in activity, and their rebuilding hastens its eventual recovery. An [[output gap]] develops between the level of output and its former trend, and there is an increase in [[unemployment]]. Prices tend to fall in response to the reduction in demand  and, if the recession persists, there is a danger of [[deflation]]. The economy's [[automatic stabilisers]] cause tax revenues to fall and benefit payments to rise, causing an increase in the [[budget deficit]]. Depending on the pre-recession level of the foreign-held [[public debt]] as a percentage GDP  and the prospects of a return to growth, the market may add a [[risk premium]] to the [[yield (finance)|yield]] that it expects from the government's [[bond]]s to compensate for the perceived risk of [[sovereign default]]. If the market's concern about the government in question develops into one of [[debt aversion]], the premium may rise to a point at which the government finds it difficult to avoid [[default (finance)|default]].
A more persistent form of recession (termed a [[balance sheet recession]]<ref>[http://www.house.gov/apps/list/hearing/financialsvcs_dem/richardc.koo.pdf Richard C. Koo:  ''U.S. Economy in Balance Sheet Recession: What the U.S. Can Learn from Japan’s Experience in 1990–2005'', Testimony to the House of Representatives Financial Services Committee, 10th February 2010]</ref>
<ref>[http://ineteconomics.org/sites/inet.civicactions.net/files/koo_testimony.pdf Richard C. Koo ''How to Avoid a Third Depression'', Testimony before the Committee on Financial Services of the U.S. House of Representatives, July 22, 2010]</ref>)
can develop when consumers and firms find themselves unable to [[roll-over]] their debts  because the bursting of an[[asset price bubble]]s had reduced the value of the [[collateral]] at their disposal. The  reductions in spending required  to achieve  the necessary  debt reductions (sometimes called [[deleveraging]]) continue until sustainable debt levels have been restored.


==Remedies==
==Remedies==
Until the 1930s, the prevailing attitude to recessions  was passive acceptance - in accordance with the teaching of the [[Austrian School of economics]]. Harvard's Joseph Schumpeter argued that "depressions are not simply evils, which we might attempt to suppress, but forms of something which has to be done, namely, adjustment to change."<ref>[[Joseph A. Schumpeter]], ''[http://books.google.com/books?id=MlXr6e4Opo0C&pg=PA117 Essays on Entrepreneurs, Innovations, Business Cycles, and the Evolution of Capitalism]'' (Transaction Publishers, 1989)]</ref>.  In the 1930s, limited use was made of [[public expenditure]]  to counter the [[Great Depression]], and the  use of  [[fiscal stimulus|fiscal stimuluses]] as proposed by [[John Maynard Keynes]] gained general acceptance in the 1940s. That remedy was widely abandoned in the 1980s in favour of the use of [[monetary policy]] to regulate the [[output gap]] by varying short-term interest rates. In the course of the [[Great Recession]] of 2007-10 that form of monetary policy was augmented by the use of [[quantitative easing]] to expand the [[money supply]], and there was a temporary return to the use of [[fiscal policy]].
Until the 1930s, the prevailing attitude to recessions  was passive acceptance - in accordance with the teaching of the [[Austrian School of economics]]. Harvard's Joseph Schumpeter argued that "depressions are not simply evils, which we might attempt to suppress, but forms of something which has to be done, namely, adjustment to change."<ref>[[Joseph A. Schumpeter]], ''[http://books.google.com/books?id=MlXr6e4Opo0C&pg=PA117 Essays on Entrepreneurs, Innovations, Business Cycles, and the Evolution of Capitalism]'' (Transaction Publishers, 1989)]</ref>.  In the 1930s, limited use was made of [[public expenditure]]  to counter the [[Great Depression]], and the  use of  [[fiscal stimulus|fiscal stimuluses]] as proposed by [[John Maynard Keynes]] gained general acceptance in the 1940s. That remedy was widely abandoned in the 1980s in favour of the use of [[monetary policy]] to regulate the [[output gap]] by varying short-term interest rates. In the course of the [[Great Recession]] of 2007-10that form of monetary policy was augmented by the use of [[quantitative easing]] o expand the [[money supply]], and there was a temporary return to the use of [[fiscal policy]].


==The costs of recessions==
==The costs of recessions==
Recessions impose costs on the community in terms of loss of output, and of reductions in the welbeing of its people.
Recessions impose costs on the community in terms of loss of output, and of reductions in the well-being of its people.


The value of the reduction in output that occurs in the course of a recession depends pattern  of the decline and recovery of output, but the proportion that subsequently remains is determined solely by the nature of recovery . Among the determinants of the speed of recovery, budget deficits have had a positive influence,<ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2009/wp09183.pdf Valerie Cerra, Ugo Panizza, and Sweta C. Saxena: ''International Evidence on Recovery from Recessions'' International Monetary Fund Working Paper, August 2009]</ref>  but, even where the recovery has been rapid, there have been permanent output losses<ref>[http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/staffp/2005/01/cerra.htm Valerie Cerra and Sweta Chaman Saxena: ''Did Output Recover from the Asian Crisis?'', International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, April 2005]</ref>. Long-term costs may also arise from recession-induced losses of physical and [[humam capital]].
The loss of output that occurs during a recession may be accompanied by a loss of productive capacity, because  of reductions in physical capital, [[human capital]] or [[social capital]]<ref>[http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/staffp/2005/01/cerra.htm Valerie Cerra and Sweta Chaman Saxena: ''Did Output Recover from the Asian Crisis?'', International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, April 2005]</ref>, leading to a drop in the level from which output growth resumes.


Workers that lose their jobs have suffered  losses  of income, and it has been estimated that they have suffered psychological harm that was as much as three times as important to them<ref>[http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=984248 Andreas Knabe and Steffen Raetze: ''Quantifying the Non-Pecuniary Costs of Unemployment: The Role of Permanent Income'', FEMM Working Paper No. 12/2007, April 2007]</ref>. Fear of unemployment is also psychologically harmful,  even to the extent of being an important predictor of psychological symptons<ref> Catherine Marsh and Carolyn Vogler (eds): ''Social Change and the Experience of Unemployment'' pp191-212, Oxford University Press 1994 [http://www.questia.com/read/74455918?title=Social%20Change%20and%20the%20Experience%20of%20Unemployment#](Questia subscribers)</ref>. The loss of employment by  family wage earners has been found to  be particularly burdensome because it cuts deeply into their sense of obligation, their identity, and their status;  and unemployment after marriage has been found to increase the incidence of divorce.
Workers that lose their jobs have suffered  psychological damage as well as losses  of income, and it has been estimated that the psychological harm may have been  as much as three times as important to them as the loss of income <ref>[http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=984248 Andreas Knabe and Steffen Raetze: ''Quantifying the Non-Pecuniary Costs of Unemployment: The Role of Permanent Income'', FEMM Working Paper No. 12/2007, April 2007]</ref>. Fear of unemployment is also psychologically harmful,  even to the extent of being an important predictor of psychological symptoms<ref> Catherine Marsh and Carolyn Vogler (eds): ''Social Change and the Experience of Unemployment'' pp191-212, Oxford University Press 1994 [http://www.questia.com/read/74455918?title=Social%20Change%20and%20the%20Experience%20of%20Unemployment#](Questia subscribers)</ref>. The loss of employment by  family wage earners has been found to  be particularly burdensome because it cuts deeply into their sense of obligation, their identity, and their status;  and unemployment after marriage has been found to increase the incidence of divorce.
<ref>[http://www.allacademic.com//meta/p_mla_apa_research_citation/2/4/0/3/4/pages240344/p240344-1.php Cristobal Young: ''Unemployment, Income, and Subjective Well-Being: Non-Pecuniary Costs of Unemployment'', allacademic, October 2007]</ref>. It has also been found that unemployed men are less healthy and have a higher mortality than employed men
<ref>[http://www.allacademic.com//meta/p_mla_apa_research_citation/2/4/0/3/4/pages240344/p240344-1.php Cristobal Young: ''Unemployment, Income, and Subjective Well-Being: Non-Pecuniary Costs of Unemployment'', allacademic, October 2007]</ref>. It has also been found that unemployed men are less healthy and have a higher mortality than employed men
<ref>[http://www.bmj.com/cgi/content/full/338/mar10_2/b829 Danny Dorling: ''Unemployment and Health'', British Medical Journal, 10 March 2009]</ref>.
<ref>[http://www.bmj.com/cgi/content/full/338/mar10_2/b829 Danny Dorling: ''Unemployment and Health'', British Medical Journal, 10 March 2009]</ref>.
The social costs of recessions are  increased if governments reduce social security spending in order  to offset the inevitable fall in tax revenues without increasing their  borrowing.  Such was the common practice before the second world war. It is unavoidable for  a country  whose government  cannot increase its borrowing because its  level of debt is  already near  the limit of [[fiscal sustainability]], and it happens to any  country whose  government is ideologically [[debt aversion|debt averse]].
==The fiscal effects of recessions==
:''(further treatment of this topic is available in the article on [[fiscal policy]])''
The component of a country's [[budget deficit]] that arises from recession-induced falls in tax revenues and increases in social spending  is termed its [[cyclical deficit]],  to distinguish it from the [[structural deficit]] that persists in the absence of recessionary influences. However, there is often a recession-induced increase in a country's structural deficit as a result of a permanent loss in productive capacity. A country's [[fiscal sustainability]] depends upon the product of its [[public debt]] as a proportion of its GDP, and the difference between its GDP growth rate and the interest rate payable on its [[bond]]s.  Consequently it can be improved by measures that reduce the public debt,  by measures that increase GDP growth, and by measures that reduce  the fears  of  [[default (finance)|default]] on the part of bond market investors.


==Recessions in history==
==Recessions in history==
===Overview===


===The nineteenth century===
===The nineteenth century===
Line 38: Line 45:
In Britain there were credit-related recessions in 1826 and 1847, and an exceptionally severe downturn in 1858 which was partly a reflection of events in the United States <ref>[http://www.questia.com/read/61649391 J D Chambers: ''The Workshop of the World; British Economic History from 1820 to 1880'', Chapter 6, Oxford University Press, 1961]</ref>,  and a downturn in 1890 triggered by the failure of the Barings bank due to losses affecting its Latin American investments.
In Britain there were credit-related recessions in 1826 and 1847, and an exceptionally severe downturn in 1858 which was partly a reflection of events in the United States <ref>[http://www.questia.com/read/61649391 J D Chambers: ''The Workshop of the World; British Economic History from 1820 to 1880'', Chapter 6, Oxford University Press, 1961]</ref>,  and a downturn in 1890 triggered by the failure of the Barings bank due to losses affecting its Latin American investments.


The episode that was colloqually known as the "Great Depression of 1873" may not even have been a recession as that term is now defined, but only a protracted reduction in economic growth that continued intermittently until 1895 (although, according to definition used by the United States National Bureau of Economic Research, there were several recessions during that period <ref>[http://www.nber.org/cycles/ ''Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions'' National Bureau of Economic Research 2003]</ref>). Its distinguishing feature was its length rather than its depth, and also the fact that it had an unprecedentedly internationl impact
The episode that was colloquially known as the "Great Depression of 1873" may not even have been a recession as that term is now defined, but only a protracted reduction in economic growth that continued intermittently until 1895 (although, according to definition used by the United States National Bureau of Economic Research, there were several recessions during that period <ref>[http://www.nber.org/cycles/ ''Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions'' National Bureau of Economic Research 2003]</ref>). Its distinguishing feature was its length rather than its depth, and also the fact that it had an unprecedented international impact


===The twentieth century===
===The twentieth century===
Line 44: Line 51:
The only major international recession in the inter-war years was the global [[Great Depression]] that followed the American stock exchange [[crash of 1929]] the triggering of which has variously been attributed to the bursting of a speculative stock exchange bubble and to a monetary shock administered by the United States [[Federal Reserve System]], leading to persistent [[deflation]]. From its origin in the United States, it spread to other industrialised countries, resulting in  massive unemployment and human suffering. It lasted in the United States from 1930 until the outbreak of the second world war in 1939.
The only major international recession in the inter-war years was the global [[Great Depression]] that followed the American stock exchange [[crash of 1929]] the triggering of which has variously been attributed to the bursting of a speculative stock exchange bubble and to a monetary shock administered by the United States [[Federal Reserve System]], leading to persistent [[deflation]]. From its origin in the United States, it spread to other industrialised countries, resulting in  massive unemployment and human suffering. It lasted in the United States from 1930 until the outbreak of the second world war in 1939.


The most important of the international recessions that occurred in the post-war years of the twentieth century were the global [[recession of 1973]], triggered by the sudden rise in the price of oil, and an Asian recession in the 1990s triggered by the bursting of a real-estate buble and the consequential development of the [[Asian banking crises]].
The most important of the international recessions that occurred in the post-war years of the twentieth century were the global [[recession of 1973]], triggered by the sudden rise in the price of oil, and an Asian recession in the 1990s triggered by the bursting of a real-estate bubble and the consequential development of the [[Asian banking crises]].


In addition to the international recessions there were numerous national recessions <ref> Including 13 recessions in the United States [http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc1/Recessions.html][http://recessionhistory.info/].</ref>.
In addition to the international recessions there were numerous national recessions <ref> Including 13 recessions in the United States [http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc1/Recessions.html][http://recessionhistory.info/].</ref>.
Line 51: Line 58:


The [[Great Recession]] of 2007-2010  is largely attributable to the banking and credit [[crash of 2008]] which was triggered by the bursting of a speculative real-estate [[bubble (economics)|bubble]] in the United States, and the following [[subprime mortgage crisis]].
The [[Great Recession]] of 2007-2010  is largely attributable to the banking and credit [[crash of 2008]] which was triggered by the bursting of a speculative real-estate [[bubble (economics)|bubble]] in the United States, and the following [[subprime mortgage crisis]].
==The causes of recessions==
The causation of recessions is a topic of continuing controversy among economists, and is at the heart of the study of [[macroeconomics]], but there is general agreement concerning some of  their common characteristics. By common consent a recession is  generally triggered by a failure of  the [[market]] mechanisms that normally keep supply in line with demand. The result is a deficiency of demand, meaning that suppliers are unable to sell their output  - and that, in particular, many people find themselves unable to get [[employment]] (a simple explanation of its occurrence is provided Richard Sweeney's [[/Tutorials#The baby-sitting crisis - an analogy|baby-sitting analogy]]). The breakdown of the market mechanism is often triggered by an economic "shock" that reduces consumer confidence.
Persistent recessions have been [[balance sheet recession]]s<ref>[http://www.house.gov/apps/list/hearing/financialsvcs_dem/richardc.koo.pdf Richard C. Koo:  ''U.S. Economy in Balance Sheet Recession: What the U.S. Can Learn from Japan’s Experience in 1990–2005'', Testimony to the House of Representatives Financial Services Committee, 10th February 2010]</ref>
<ref>[http://ineteconomics.org/sites/inet.civicactions.net/files/koo_testimony.pdf Richard C. Koo ''How to Avoid a Third Depression'', Testimony before the Committee on Financial Services of the U.S. House of Representatives, July 22, 2010]</ref>
triggered the bursting of speculative [[asset price bubble]]s.
More commonly, recessions have been brought about by sudden increases of commodity prices, or credit shortages resulting from financial crises. The initial fall in demand usually prompts firms to run down their stocks, which depresses activity among their suppliers. The re-stocking that occurs when consumer demand starts to rise again tends to speed the recovery and, according to the "Zarnowitz rule", the steeper  the initial downturn in activity, the more rapid will be the subsequent upturn<ref>Victor Zarnowitz: ''What is a Business Cycle?'', NBER Working Paper No. W3863, National Bureau of Economic Research, October 1991</ref> (but that rule may not hold for balance sheet recessions).


==References==
==References==
{{reflist|2}}
{{reflist|2}}

Latest revision as of 19:47, 7 March 2024

This article is a stub and thus not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.

Recessions have punctuated the growth of the major economies from time to time since the 18th century, causing losses of productive capacity and of human capital. Various remedies have been tried, and it was thought for a time in the late 20th century that a cure had been found. The Great Recession has put an end to that belief and has created a renewed interest in the phenomenon.

Terminology

The terms recession and depression are used colloquially to describe any deep or persistent decline in economic activity, (and sometimes to a persistent reduction in the rate of growth of ouput). More precise definitions have been adopted the statistics authorities. In the United States the National Bureau of Economic Research defines a recession as

a significant decline in economic activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, and wholesale retail sales[1][2]

Other authorities have not adopted a formal definition of recession but most commentators and analysts use

a period of of negative growth of real (inflation-adjusted) GDP lasting for at least two quarters[3].

The term double-dip recession refers to a second fall in economic growth following an aborted recovery from a recession, such as occurred in the 1937-39 phase of the Great Depression. The terms downturn, and "trough" are used to denote the onset of negative growth, and the point at which positive growth resumes.

Before 1930, what are now termed recessions were referred to as "depressions". That term is nowadays reserved for exceptionally severe or prolonged recessions. Again there is no formal definition, but it has been suggested that the term be applied to a decline in real GDP that exceeds 10%, or one that lasts more than three years[4].

The causes of recessions

The causation of recessions is a topic of continuing controversy among economists, and is at the heart of the study of macroeconomics, but there is general agreement concerning some of their common characteristics. By common consent a recession is generally triggered by a failure of the market mechanisms that normally keep supply in line with demand. The result is a deficiency of demand, meaning that suppliers are unable to sell their output - and that, in particular, many people find themselves unable to get employment (a simple explanation of its occurrence is provided Richard Sweeney's baby-sitting analogy). The breakdown of the market mechanism is often triggered by an economic "shock" that reduces consumer confidence.

Recessions have commonly been brought about by sudden increases of commodity prices, or by credit shortages resulting from financial crises. As a result, consumers and firms are prompted (or forced) to cut back on their spending. The fall in spending then prompts suppliers to run down their stocks, which depresses activity among their suppliers and causes a further fall in aggregate demand. Previously employed resources of capital and labour fall out of use and a growing output gap develops between actual and potential output (which is reflected in a gap between the growth rate of GDP and its former trend) and there is an increase in unemployment. A recovery normally follows as prices fall in response to the reduction in demand, and as benefit payments and other social security payments rise. As consumer demand recovers, re-stocking by suppliers tends to speed the recovery in economic activity. (According to the "Zarnowitz rule", the steeper the initial downturn in activity, the more rapid will be the subsequent upturn[5] (but that rule may not hold for balance sheet recessions).

A more persistent form of recession (termed a balance sheet recession[6] [7]) can develop when consumers and firms find themselves unable to roll-over their debts because the bursting of anasset price bubbles had reduced the value of the collateral at their disposal. The reductions in spending required to achieve the necessary debt reductions (sometimes called deleveraging) continue until sustainable debt levels have been restored.

Remedies

Until the 1930s, the prevailing attitude to recessions was passive acceptance - in accordance with the teaching of the Austrian School of economics. Harvard's Joseph Schumpeter argued that "depressions are not simply evils, which we might attempt to suppress, but forms of something which has to be done, namely, adjustment to change."[8]. In the 1930s, limited use was made of public expenditure to counter the Great Depression, and the use of fiscal stimuluses as proposed by John Maynard Keynes gained general acceptance in the 1940s. That remedy was widely abandoned in the 1980s in favour of the use of monetary policy to regulate the output gap by varying short-term interest rates. In the course of the Great Recession of 2007-10, that form of monetary policy was augmented by the use of quantitative easing o expand the money supply, and there was a temporary return to the use of fiscal policy.

The costs of recessions

Recessions impose costs on the community in terms of loss of output, and of reductions in the well-being of its people.

The loss of output that occurs during a recession may be accompanied by a loss of productive capacity, because of reductions in physical capital, human capital or social capital[9], leading to a drop in the level from which output growth resumes.

Workers that lose their jobs have suffered psychological damage as well as losses of income, and it has been estimated that the psychological harm may have been as much as three times as important to them as the loss of income [10]. Fear of unemployment is also psychologically harmful, even to the extent of being an important predictor of psychological symptoms[11]. The loss of employment by family wage earners has been found to be particularly burdensome because it cuts deeply into their sense of obligation, their identity, and their status; and unemployment after marriage has been found to increase the incidence of divorce. [12]. It has also been found that unemployed men are less healthy and have a higher mortality than employed men [13].

The social costs of recessions are increased if governments reduce social security spending in order to offset the inevitable fall in tax revenues without increasing their borrowing. Such was the common practice before the second world war. It is unavoidable for a country whose government cannot increase its borrowing because its level of debt is already near the limit of fiscal sustainability, and it happens to any country whose government is ideologically debt averse.

The fiscal effects of recessions

(further treatment of this topic is available in the article on fiscal policy)

The component of a country's budget deficit that arises from recession-induced falls in tax revenues and increases in social spending is termed its cyclical deficit, to distinguish it from the structural deficit that persists in the absence of recessionary influences. However, there is often a recession-induced increase in a country's structural deficit as a result of a permanent loss in productive capacity. A country's fiscal sustainability depends upon the product of its public debt as a proportion of its GDP, and the difference between its GDP growth rate and the interest rate payable on its bonds. Consequently it can be improved by measures that reduce the public debt, by measures that increase GDP growth, and by measures that reduce the fears of default on the part of bond market investors.

Recessions in history

The nineteenth century

There are reported to have been eleven recessions of varying severity in the United States between 1865 and 1900 the worst of which was the panic of 1893 in which a monetary crisis led to the failure of 500 banks and an unemployment rate of over ten per cent.

In Britain there were credit-related recessions in 1826 and 1847, and an exceptionally severe downturn in 1858 which was partly a reflection of events in the United States [14], and a downturn in 1890 triggered by the failure of the Barings bank due to losses affecting its Latin American investments.

The episode that was colloquially known as the "Great Depression of 1873" may not even have been a recession as that term is now defined, but only a protracted reduction in economic growth that continued intermittently until 1895 (although, according to definition used by the United States National Bureau of Economic Research, there were several recessions during that period [15]). Its distinguishing feature was its length rather than its depth, and also the fact that it had an unprecedented international impact

The twentieth century

The only major international recession in the inter-war years was the global Great Depression that followed the American stock exchange crash of 1929 the triggering of which has variously been attributed to the bursting of a speculative stock exchange bubble and to a monetary shock administered by the United States Federal Reserve System, leading to persistent deflation. From its origin in the United States, it spread to other industrialised countries, resulting in massive unemployment and human suffering. It lasted in the United States from 1930 until the outbreak of the second world war in 1939.

The most important of the international recessions that occurred in the post-war years of the twentieth century were the global recession of 1973, triggered by the sudden rise in the price of oil, and an Asian recession in the 1990s triggered by the bursting of a real-estate bubble and the consequential development of the Asian banking crises.

In addition to the international recessions there were numerous national recessions [16].

The twenty-first century

The Great Recession of 2007-2010 is largely attributable to the banking and credit crash of 2008 which was triggered by the bursting of a speculative real-estate bubble in the United States, and the following subprime mortgage crisis.

References

  1. Recession: how is that defined?, Bureau of Economics, US Department of Commerce
  2. For a further explanation and some examples see What Is a Recession And Are We In One? Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland October 2008
  3. Stijn Claessens and M. Ayhan Kose: What Is a Recession?, International Monetary Fund, March 2009
  4. Diagnosing depression, The Economist, Dec 30th 2008
  5. Victor Zarnowitz: What is a Business Cycle?, NBER Working Paper No. W3863, National Bureau of Economic Research, October 1991
  6. Richard C. Koo: U.S. Economy in Balance Sheet Recession: What the U.S. Can Learn from Japan’s Experience in 1990–2005, Testimony to the House of Representatives Financial Services Committee, 10th February 2010
  7. Richard C. Koo How to Avoid a Third Depression, Testimony before the Committee on Financial Services of the U.S. House of Representatives, July 22, 2010
  8. Joseph A. Schumpeter, Essays on Entrepreneurs, Innovations, Business Cycles, and the Evolution of Capitalism (Transaction Publishers, 1989)]
  9. Valerie Cerra and Sweta Chaman Saxena: Did Output Recover from the Asian Crisis?, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, April 2005
  10. Andreas Knabe and Steffen Raetze: Quantifying the Non-Pecuniary Costs of Unemployment: The Role of Permanent Income, FEMM Working Paper No. 12/2007, April 2007
  11. Catherine Marsh and Carolyn Vogler (eds): Social Change and the Experience of Unemployment pp191-212, Oxford University Press 1994 [1](Questia subscribers)
  12. Cristobal Young: Unemployment, Income, and Subjective Well-Being: Non-Pecuniary Costs of Unemployment, allacademic, October 2007
  13. Danny Dorling: Unemployment and Health, British Medical Journal, 10 March 2009
  14. J D Chambers: The Workshop of the World; British Economic History from 1820 to 1880, Chapter 6, Oxford University Press, 1961
  15. Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions National Bureau of Economic Research 2003
  16. Including 13 recessions in the United States [2][3].