Recession of 2009: Difference between revisions
imported>Nick Gardner No edit summary |
imported>Nick Gardner No edit summary |
||
Line 2: | Line 2: | ||
{{TOC|right}} | {{TOC|right}} | ||
:''(The title of this article reflects the fact that the full intensity of the recession did not develop until 2009 | :''(The title of this article reflects the fact that the full intensity of the recession did not develop until 2009 and the fact that recovery was incomplete at the end of that year'' | ||
Downturns in economic growth rates were apparent early in 2008, and the subsequent intensification of the financial [[crash of 2008]] led to a general expectation of worse to come. The resulting loss of confidence by investors and consumers contributed further to the severity of the reduction in world economic growth, and it was apparent by the end of 2008 that the economies of the United States and several European countries had for some time been in recession. An impending collapse of the international financial system was averted by policy actions introduced in the winter of 2008, but credit availability had been only partly restored by the spring of 2009. | Downturns in economic growth rates were apparent early in 2008, and the subsequent intensification of the financial [[crash of 2008]] led to a general expectation of worse to come. The resulting loss of confidence by investors and consumers contributed further to the severity of the reduction in world economic growth, and it was apparent by the end of 2008 that the economies of the United States and several European countries had for some time been in recession. An impending collapse of the international financial system was averted by policy actions introduced in the winter of 2008, but credit availability had been only partly restored by the spring of 2009. | ||
Line 16: | Line 16: | ||
Throughout the period from mid-2007 to mid-2008, the growth of the world economy was hampered by increases in oil and food prices, and by a crisis in the financial markets. Oil prices rose from $75 to $146 a barrel and food prices rose sharply, forcing householders to cut their spending on other products. On the financial markets, the [[subprime mortgage crisis]] developed into the [[crash of 2008]], as a result of which the availability of credit to households and businesses was curtailed, leading to further reductions in household spending and business investment. In the nine months to the middle of 2008, the advanced economies had grown at an annual rate of only one per cent (compared with two and a half per cent in the previous nine months) and the growth rate of the developing economies had eased from eight per cent to seven and a half per cent. According to the OECD <ref>[http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/60/54/41812368.pdf ''Economic Survey of the United States'', OECD December 2008]</ref> the US economy was by then already facing substantial difficulties. Households had borrowed at an unprecedented rate during the previous 15 years, and their saving rates had fallen nearly to zero as they increasingly relied on housing wealth to finance consumption. With the housing market suffering the severest correction for 50 years, household wealth was declining, and with credit conditions getting tighter, households had been forced to reduce their reliance on borrowing, and job losses and mortgage foreclosures were rising. The prospects of a recession in the United States and of severe reductions in economic growth elsewhere were becoming apparent when the world economy was hit by another shock. The failure of the Lehman Brothers investment bank in September caused am international ''banking panic'' that triggered an intensification of the credit shortage to the point at which the world’s financial system appeared to be on the verge of collapse. Massive financial support to their banks by the governments of the industrialised countries averted that collapse, but failed to restore the supply of credit to businesses and householders. By that time, demand reductions had led to reductions in the prices of oil and food, but the resulting relief of the downward pressure on demand was being outweighed by the mounting effects of the credit shortage. By the end of September the United States economy had been in recession for nine months with no apparent prospect of an early recovery and by the end of the year, most of the industrialised countries had suffered reductions in economic activity. After that it soon become evident that a world-wide recession was under way. | Throughout the period from mid-2007 to mid-2008, the growth of the world economy was hampered by increases in oil and food prices, and by a crisis in the financial markets. Oil prices rose from $75 to $146 a barrel and food prices rose sharply, forcing householders to cut their spending on other products. On the financial markets, the [[subprime mortgage crisis]] developed into the [[crash of 2008]], as a result of which the availability of credit to households and businesses was curtailed, leading to further reductions in household spending and business investment. In the nine months to the middle of 2008, the advanced economies had grown at an annual rate of only one per cent (compared with two and a half per cent in the previous nine months) and the growth rate of the developing economies had eased from eight per cent to seven and a half per cent. According to the OECD <ref>[http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/60/54/41812368.pdf ''Economic Survey of the United States'', OECD December 2008]</ref> the US economy was by then already facing substantial difficulties. Households had borrowed at an unprecedented rate during the previous 15 years, and their saving rates had fallen nearly to zero as they increasingly relied on housing wealth to finance consumption. With the housing market suffering the severest correction for 50 years, household wealth was declining, and with credit conditions getting tighter, households had been forced to reduce their reliance on borrowing, and job losses and mortgage foreclosures were rising. The prospects of a recession in the United States and of severe reductions in economic growth elsewhere were becoming apparent when the world economy was hit by another shock. The failure of the Lehman Brothers investment bank in September caused am international ''banking panic'' that triggered an intensification of the credit shortage to the point at which the world’s financial system appeared to be on the verge of collapse. Massive financial support to their banks by the governments of the industrialised countries averted that collapse, but failed to restore the supply of credit to businesses and householders. By that time, demand reductions had led to reductions in the prices of oil and food, but the resulting relief of the downward pressure on demand was being outweighed by the mounting effects of the credit shortage. By the end of September the United States economy had been in recession for nine months with no apparent prospect of an early recovery and by the end of the year, most of the industrialised countries had suffered reductions in economic activity. After that it soon become evident that a world-wide recession was under way. | ||
== | ==Economic recovery== | ||
Leading indicators for April 2009 were showing slight signs that the leading economies might have started to return to their long-term trends<ref> See the [[/Addendum|addendum subpage]]</ref> and in June, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board spoke of indications that the pace of economic contraction may be slowing<ref>http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20090603a.htm. Ben Bernanke'c testimomy to the Committee on the Budget, U.S. House of Representatives, Washington, D.C. | Leading indicators for April 2009 were showing slight signs that the leading economies might have started to return to their long-term trends<ref> See the [[/Addendum|addendum subpage]]</ref> and in June, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board spoke of indications that the pace of economic contraction may be slowing<ref>http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20090603a.htm. Ben Bernanke'c testimomy to the Committee on the Budget, U.S. House of Representatives, Washington, D.C. | ||
June 3, 2009]</ref>. | June 3, 2009]</ref>. | ||
== | ==Fiscal recovery== | ||
==The policy debate== | |||
== | |||
===Overview=== | ===Overview=== | ||
As the recession deepened, budget deficits widened, mainly as a result of the operation of ''automatic stabilisers'', but also as a result of discretionary ''fiscal stimuluses''. A | As the recession deepened, budget deficits widened, mainly as a result of the operation of ''automatic stabilisers'', but also as a result of discretionary ''fiscal stimuluses''. A conflict developed between those who fear that the resulting fiscal expansion may be insufficient to counter growing ''output gaps'' - and those who consider fiscal policy to be unnecessary or ineffective - or who fear the possibility of ''sovereign default''. Among the first group were the Nobel prize-winners Paul Krugman <ref>[http://www.nytimes.com/2009/01/09/opinion/09krugman.html?partner=rssnyt&emc=rss Paul Krugman ''The Obama Gap'', New York Times blog 8 January 2009]</ref>, and Joseph Stiglitz <ref>[http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/stiglitz110/English Joseph Stiglitz "How to Fail to Recover", Project Syndicate, 2009.]</ref>. Among the others were the Chicago School's Eugene Fama, and a group of eminent British economists who argued that "occasional slowdowns are natural and necessary features of a market economy" and that "insofar as they are to be managed at all, the best tools are monetary and not fiscal ones"<ref>[http://www.iea.org.uk/record.jsp?type=pressArticle&ID=376 ''Keynesian Over-spending Won't Rescue the Economy", Letter by IEA economists in the Sunday Telegraph, 26 October 2008]</ref>. | ||
===The case for fiscal expansion=== | ===The case for fiscal expansion=== |
Revision as of 06:45, 6 October 2009
- (The title of this article reflects the fact that the full intensity of the recession did not develop until 2009 and the fact that recovery was incomplete at the end of that year
Downturns in economic growth rates were apparent early in 2008, and the subsequent intensification of the financial crash of 2008 led to a general expectation of worse to come. The resulting loss of confidence by investors and consumers contributed further to the severity of the reduction in world economic growth, and it was apparent by the end of 2008 that the economies of the United States and several European countries had for some time been in recession. An impending collapse of the international financial system was averted by policy actions introduced in the winter of 2008, but credit availability had been only partly restored by the spring of 2009.
- Supplementary material:
- for definitions of terms shown in italics, see the glossary on the Related Articles subpage;
- for forecasts and a summary of recent economic developments see the Addendum subpage;
- for a sequential list of events with links to further information, see Timelines subpage; and,
- for a selection of economic statistics see the Tutorials subpage.
The downturn
Throughout the period from mid-2007 to mid-2008, the growth of the world economy was hampered by increases in oil and food prices, and by a crisis in the financial markets. Oil prices rose from $75 to $146 a barrel and food prices rose sharply, forcing householders to cut their spending on other products. On the financial markets, the subprime mortgage crisis developed into the crash of 2008, as a result of which the availability of credit to households and businesses was curtailed, leading to further reductions in household spending and business investment. In the nine months to the middle of 2008, the advanced economies had grown at an annual rate of only one per cent (compared with two and a half per cent in the previous nine months) and the growth rate of the developing economies had eased from eight per cent to seven and a half per cent. According to the OECD [1] the US economy was by then already facing substantial difficulties. Households had borrowed at an unprecedented rate during the previous 15 years, and their saving rates had fallen nearly to zero as they increasingly relied on housing wealth to finance consumption. With the housing market suffering the severest correction for 50 years, household wealth was declining, and with credit conditions getting tighter, households had been forced to reduce their reliance on borrowing, and job losses and mortgage foreclosures were rising. The prospects of a recession in the United States and of severe reductions in economic growth elsewhere were becoming apparent when the world economy was hit by another shock. The failure of the Lehman Brothers investment bank in September caused am international banking panic that triggered an intensification of the credit shortage to the point at which the world’s financial system appeared to be on the verge of collapse. Massive financial support to their banks by the governments of the industrialised countries averted that collapse, but failed to restore the supply of credit to businesses and householders. By that time, demand reductions had led to reductions in the prices of oil and food, but the resulting relief of the downward pressure on demand was being outweighed by the mounting effects of the credit shortage. By the end of September the United States economy had been in recession for nine months with no apparent prospect of an early recovery and by the end of the year, most of the industrialised countries had suffered reductions in economic activity. After that it soon become evident that a world-wide recession was under way.
Economic recovery
Leading indicators for April 2009 were showing slight signs that the leading economies might have started to return to their long-term trends[2] and in June, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board spoke of indications that the pace of economic contraction may be slowing[3].
Fiscal recovery
The policy debate
Overview
As the recession deepened, budget deficits widened, mainly as a result of the operation of automatic stabilisers, but also as a result of discretionary fiscal stimuluses. A conflict developed between those who fear that the resulting fiscal expansion may be insufficient to counter growing output gaps - and those who consider fiscal policy to be unnecessary or ineffective - or who fear the possibility of sovereign default. Among the first group were the Nobel prize-winners Paul Krugman [4], and Joseph Stiglitz [5]. Among the others were the Chicago School's Eugene Fama, and a group of eminent British economists who argued that "occasional slowdowns are natural and necessary features of a market economy" and that "insofar as they are to be managed at all, the best tools are monetary and not fiscal ones"[6].
The case for fiscal expansion
By October 2008, policy-makers in most industrialised countries had accepted that in order to avoid the development of persistent and unmanageable deflation such as occurred in the pre-war great depression, early corrective action would have to be taken, going beyond the necessary restoration of activity in the financial system. Most countries had long abandoned the use of reductions of taxation and increases in public expenditure to ward off economic downturns in favour of the use of interest rate reductions [7], but there were doubts whether monetary policy would be sufficiently powerful, or sufficiently quick-acting in view if the severity and imminence of the current deflationary threat. In the United States, in particular, the federal interest rate had already been reduced to 1 per cent - leaving little scope for further reductions, and banks there and elsewhere had become reluctant to pass on central bank reductions of interest rates.
The consensus view among economists, as expressed by the Chief Economist of the OECD is that :
- Against the backdrop of a deep economic downturn, additional macroeconomic stimulus is needed. In normal times, monetary rather than fiscal policy would be the instrument of choice for macroeconomic stabilisation. But these are not normal times. Current conditions of extreme financial stress have weakened the monetary transmission mechanism. Moreover, in some countries the scope for further reductions in policy rates is limited. In this unusual situation, fiscal policy stimulus over and above the support provided through automatic stabilisers has an important role to play. Fiscal stimulus packages, however, need to be evaluated on a case-by-case basis in those countries where room for budgetary manoeuvre exists. It is vital that any discretionary action be timely and temporary and designed to ensure maximum effectiveness.[8]
In its 2008 World Economic Outlook, the International Monetary Fund has also noted that fiscal policy can quickly boost spending power, whereas monetary policy acts with long and uncertain lags [9], and a 2009 IMF Staff Position Note demonstrates that an internationally coordinated programme of fiscal expansion, combined with accommodative monetary policies, can have significant multiplier effects on the world economy [10].
The case for fiscal expansion eventually gained near-universal political acceptance, and by early 2009, nearly all the G20 countries had introduced fiscal stimulus programmes [11].
The need for fiscal space
However, the IMF also advised that a fiscal stimulus could do more harm than good if it made debt unsustainable, and suggested that further stimuli should be confined to countries with fiscal space to expand, such as the United Kingdom, China, France, Germany, and the United States [12], as compared, for example, with Japan and Italy. A spread in fears of government insolvency could hamper recovery because a perceived risk that governments might find it more convenient to repudiate their debt could lead to an increase in the cost of borrowing. They reported some signs of an increase in such fears in early 2009 and although they considered the perceived risk to be small, they considered it important that governments should present plans that would reassure markets that fiscal solvency is not at risk. [13]
Objections
Professor Eugene Fama of the University of Chicago argues that consumers do not respond to tax cuts because of awareness that they will eventually be paid for by tax increases (the argument known to economists as Ricardian Equivalence). He also argues that all forms of fiscal stimulus are ineffective because they merely move resources from private investment to government investment or from investment to consumption, with no effect on total current resources in the system or on total employment [14] (the argument known as crowding-out). Others have argued that the danger of incurring unsustainable debt [15], makes fiscal stimulus a risky option, especially for countries with high levels of national debt. There have been warnings of resulting disaster, even for countries with modest ratios of national debt to GDP. Another objection arises from the fear that expansionary fiscal and monetary policies would not be reversed in time to avoid inflation (that objection was expressed by the economist Allan Meltzer [16] in the same issue of the New York Times in which the economist Paul Krugman was advocating a further stimulus in order to avert the danger of deflation [17]).
References
- ↑ Economic Survey of the United States, OECD December 2008
- ↑ See the addendum subpage
- ↑ http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20090603a.htm. Ben Bernanke'c testimomy to the Committee on the Budget, U.S. House of Representatives, Washington, D.C. June 3, 2009]
- ↑ Paul Krugman The Obama Gap, New York Times blog 8 January 2009
- ↑ Joseph Stiglitz "How to Fail to Recover", Project Syndicate, 2009.
- ↑ Keynesian Over-spending Won't Rescue the Economy", Letter by IEA economists in the Sunday Telegraph, 26 October 2008
- ↑ For an account of the reasons for use of interest rates for economic stabilisation, see the paragraph on monetary policy in the article on macroeconomics, and for a description of the techniques that are employed, see paragraph 3 of the article on banking., and in other
- ↑ Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel: A Long Recession" ,Editorial to OECD Observer No 270, December 2008
- ↑ Fiscal Policy as a Countercyclical Tool, IMF World Economic Outlook, Chapter 5 , October 2008
- ↑ Charles Freedman, Michael Kumhof, Douglas Laxton, and Jaewoo Lee: The Case for Global Fiscal Stimulus, IMF Staff Position Note SPN/09/03, International Monetary Fund, March 6 2009
- ↑ Eswar Prasad: Assessing the G-20 Stimulus Plans: A Deeper Look, Brookings Institution May 2009
- ↑ Mark Horton and Anna Ivanova: "The Size of the Fiscal Expansion: An Analysis for the Largest Countries", IMF Fiscal Department Note, February 2009
- ↑ "The State of Public Finances: Outlook and Medium-Term Policies After the 2008 Crisis" IMF March 6 2009
- ↑ Eugene Fama: Bailouts and Stimulus Plans January 2009
- ↑ The conditions for fiscal sustainability are set out in paragraph 4.1 of the article on national debt [1]
- ↑ Allan Meltzer: Inflation Nation, New York Times op-ed, 3rd May 2009
- ↑ Paul Krugman: Falling Wage Syndrome, New York Times op-ed, 3rd May 2009