Deflation: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
No edit summary
mNo edit summary
 
(40 intermediate revisions by 3 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{subpages}}
{{subpages}}


Defined as a sustained fall in the general level of prices, '''deflation''' can be the result of a sudden decline in economic activity.  
Defined as a sustained fall in the general level of prices, '''deflation''' is not necessarily harmful, but there there is a danger that it could have disastrous economic consequences.


Its  immediate effect is to make consumers reduce their purchases in the expectation of being able to buy  more cheaply at a later date. A less obvious but more important effect is to require borrowers to repay more in real terms than they had borrowed.  (for example, if prices declined by 20 percent, a farmer who had previously borrowed £100 to buy ten pigs would have to repay the equivalent of twelve pigs). Another effect is to require employers to pay their employees the same wages  despite a reduction in income from their employees' output - or, to put it another way, to pay higher real wages for the same level of real output.
==The causes of deflation==
Thus deflation can disrupt the economy by prompting consumers to delay their purchases, borrowers to default on repayments and employers to dismiss their employees. Each of those responses intensifies the initial decline in activity, and each further decline in activity intensifies the responses that produced it - and so on in a devastating spiral of economic decline and rising unemployment.


   
Deflation is nowadays usually side effect of a collapse of aggregate demand--a drop in spending so severe that producers must cut prices in order to find buyers.The economic effects of a deflationary episode, for the most part, are similar to those of any other sharp decline in aggregate spending--namely, recession, rising unemployment, and financial stress.


==The effects of deflation==


===First-round effects===


Deflation tends to make consumers reduce their purchases in the expectation of being able to buy  more cheaply at a later date.  That can have a depressing effect upon demand and lead to  a reduction of output.  Another potentially important  effect is to require borrowers to repay more than they had borrowed (for example, if prices declined by 20 percent, a farmer who had previously borrowed £100 to buy ten pigs would have to repay the equivalent of twelve pigs). The resulting loss to borrowers may be  balanced by gains to lenders, but if borrowers are forced to default, the resulting  disruption can lead to a further reduction in output.  Another effect is to require employers to pay their employees the same wages  despite a reduction in income from their employees' output. Unless there is a compensating wage reduction, that  may result in a reduction in employment and another reduction in output.


<ref>[http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/siklos.deflation Pierre Siklos: ''Deflation'', Economic History Services Encyclopedia]</ref>
===Second-round effects : the "deflationary spiral"===
A sudden and unexpected deflation can  result in output losses that feed upon themselves by reinforcing the tendencies that produced them. For example the output loss from the deferrment of purchases could  lead to an increase in unemployment, which could  prompt a further reduction in spending and thus  a further increase in unemployment.


<ref> Richard Burdekin and Pierre  Siklos (eds): "Fears of Deflation and Policy Responses Then and Now." In ''Deflation: Current and Historical Perspectives'', Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004 </ref>.
==Policy responses==
Central bank policy makers  generally, recommend early preemptive action to avert the danger of deflation - on the grounds that  it is difficult to devise effective policies to counter it once it has taken hold. Their principle precautionary weapon is a rapid relaxation of monetary policy by reductions in interest rates <ref>[http://www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2002/20021121/default.htm Ben Bernanke: ''Deflation: Making Sure "It" Doesn't Happen Here'' (Remarks made at the National Economists Club, Washington, D.C. November 21, 2002) Federal Reserve Board 2002]</ref> <ref>[http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2008/html/sp081125.en.html Lorenzo Bini Smaghi, (Member of the Executive Board of the ECB): ''Careful with (the "d") words!'', speech to the  European Colloquia Series, Venice, 25 November 2008, European Central Bank 2008]</ref>. Most of them also advocate  supplementing  monetary action with short-term fiscal measures, especially when  interest rates approach zero and the [[liquidity trap]]  renders conventional monetary policy ineffective <ref>[http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/bpea_jp.pdf Paul Krugman: ''It’s Baaack! Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap'']</ref>. To deal with severe threats of deflation they also advocate supplementing interest rate cuts with direct action to increase the money supply by "printing money" (otherwise known as "''quantitative easing''"<ref> For an explanation of quantitative easing, see the article on [[banking]])</ref>). They recognise, however, that such remedies can be costly and difficult to manage. Delay is likely to reduce their effectiveness, but hurriedly-devised [[public expenditure]] projects are apt to be uneconomic. The intention would be to remove the stimulus once it had served it purpose, but public awareness of that intention could reduce its effectiveness (a quandary that prompted the economist Paul Krugman to suggest that "the way to make monetary policy effective, then, is for the central bank to credibly promise to be irresponsible" <ref>[http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/japtrap.html Paul Krugman: ''Japan's Trap" May 1998]</ref>). On the other hand, failure to reverse policy as recovery commences, creates a danger of [[inflation]]. Thus the  decision to launch  anti-deflation measures involves a balancing of risks, and their success  depends upon accurate diagnosis and rapid response to change.


<ref>[http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/bpea_jp.pdf Paul Krugman: ''It’s Baaack! Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap'']</ref>
==Historical experience==


<ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/def/2003/eng/043003.htm ''Deflation: Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options'', Findings of an Interdepartmental Task Force, International Monetary Fund, April 2003]</ref>
===General===
There had been few accounts of falling price levels until the nineteenth century, when falling prices occurred in several countries (the price level is reported to have fallen in the course of the century by a third in Britain and a half in America) <ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/def/2003/eng/043003.htm ''Deflation: Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options'', Findings of an Interdepartmental Task Force, International Monetary Fund, April 2003]</ref>. That decline in prices was not associated with a fall in demand and was not accompanied by what are now seen as deflationary effects, partly because of  compensating productivity gains. In the twentieth century by contrast the  [[Great Depression]] and the [[Japanese banking crisis]], which were the two major deflationary episodes, were both driven by falls in demand following the bursting of asset price [[Bubble (banking)|bubbles]], and led to  further and sustained, demand restrictions <ref>[http://www.bis.org/publ/work186.pdf?noframes=1 Michael Bordo and Andrew Filardo: ''Deflation in Historical Perspective'', BIS Working Paper no 186, Bank for International Settlements, November 2005]</ref>


===The great depression===
In the United States, consumer prices fell  by 24 per cent from August 1929 to March 1933 and GDP fell by almost 30 per cent. The recession itself was attributed by Irving Fisher to debt deflation <ref>[http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/docs/meltzer/fisdeb33.pdf Irving Fisher: The Dept-deflation Theory of Depressions, Econometrica 1933]</ref>, but other causative factors are nowadays considered to have been more important, and there is held to be no firm evidence concerning the contribution of deflation to the mic downturn.


===Japan's "lost decade"===


The collapse of a housing price bubble in the 1990s led to a decade-long period of deflation and economic stagnation. Simulations by [[Federal Reserve Board]] economists showed that the development of an inflationary spiral and of a deep depression were averted by remedial monetary and fiscal action, and that deflation could have been averted had that action been taken more promptly.
<ref> Alan Ahearne, Joseph Gagnon, Jane Haltmaier, and Steve Kamin and others: ''Preventing Deflation: Lessons from Japan’s Experience in the 1990s'', International Finance Discussion Papers, Number 729 Federal Reserve Board, June 2002 [http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/2002/729/ifdp729.pdf]</ref>. The policy mistakes that are believed to have prevented an earlier recovery  have been extensively examined by Paul Krugman <ref>[http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/jpage.html Paul Krugman: ''A Special Page on Japan'']</ref>


 
==References==
 
<references/>[[Category:Suggestion Bot Tag]]
 
<references/>

Latest revision as of 16:00, 5 August 2024

This article is a stub and thus not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.

Defined as a sustained fall in the general level of prices, deflation is not necessarily harmful, but there there is a danger that it could have disastrous economic consequences.

The causes of deflation

Deflation is nowadays usually side effect of a collapse of aggregate demand--a drop in spending so severe that producers must cut prices in order to find buyers.The economic effects of a deflationary episode, for the most part, are similar to those of any other sharp decline in aggregate spending--namely, recession, rising unemployment, and financial stress.

The effects of deflation

First-round effects

Deflation tends to make consumers reduce their purchases in the expectation of being able to buy more cheaply at a later date. That can have a depressing effect upon demand and lead to a reduction of output. Another potentially important effect is to require borrowers to repay more than they had borrowed (for example, if prices declined by 20 percent, a farmer who had previously borrowed £100 to buy ten pigs would have to repay the equivalent of twelve pigs). The resulting loss to borrowers may be balanced by gains to lenders, but if borrowers are forced to default, the resulting disruption can lead to a further reduction in output. Another effect is to require employers to pay their employees the same wages despite a reduction in income from their employees' output. Unless there is a compensating wage reduction, that may result in a reduction in employment and another reduction in output.

Second-round effects : the "deflationary spiral"

A sudden and unexpected deflation can result in output losses that feed upon themselves by reinforcing the tendencies that produced them. For example the output loss from the deferrment of purchases could lead to an increase in unemployment, which could prompt a further reduction in spending and thus a further increase in unemployment.

Policy responses

Central bank policy makers generally, recommend early preemptive action to avert the danger of deflation - on the grounds that it is difficult to devise effective policies to counter it once it has taken hold. Their principle precautionary weapon is a rapid relaxation of monetary policy by reductions in interest rates [1] [2]. Most of them also advocate supplementing monetary action with short-term fiscal measures, especially when interest rates approach zero and the liquidity trap renders conventional monetary policy ineffective [3]. To deal with severe threats of deflation they also advocate supplementing interest rate cuts with direct action to increase the money supply by "printing money" (otherwise known as "quantitative easing"[4]). They recognise, however, that such remedies can be costly and difficult to manage. Delay is likely to reduce their effectiveness, but hurriedly-devised public expenditure projects are apt to be uneconomic. The intention would be to remove the stimulus once it had served it purpose, but public awareness of that intention could reduce its effectiveness (a quandary that prompted the economist Paul Krugman to suggest that "the way to make monetary policy effective, then, is for the central bank to credibly promise to be irresponsible" [5]). On the other hand, failure to reverse policy as recovery commences, creates a danger of inflation. Thus the decision to launch anti-deflation measures involves a balancing of risks, and their success depends upon accurate diagnosis and rapid response to change.

Historical experience

General

There had been few accounts of falling price levels until the nineteenth century, when falling prices occurred in several countries (the price level is reported to have fallen in the course of the century by a third in Britain and a half in America) [6]. That decline in prices was not associated with a fall in demand and was not accompanied by what are now seen as deflationary effects, partly because of compensating productivity gains. In the twentieth century by contrast the Great Depression and the Japanese banking crisis, which were the two major deflationary episodes, were both driven by falls in demand following the bursting of asset price bubbles, and led to further and sustained, demand restrictions [7]

The great depression

In the United States, consumer prices fell by 24 per cent from August 1929 to March 1933 and GDP fell by almost 30 per cent. The recession itself was attributed by Irving Fisher to debt deflation [8], but other causative factors are nowadays considered to have been more important, and there is held to be no firm evidence concerning the contribution of deflation to the mic downturn.

Japan's "lost decade"

The collapse of a housing price bubble in the 1990s led to a decade-long period of deflation and economic stagnation. Simulations by Federal Reserve Board economists showed that the development of an inflationary spiral and of a deep depression were averted by remedial monetary and fiscal action, and that deflation could have been averted had that action been taken more promptly. [9]. The policy mistakes that are believed to have prevented an earlier recovery have been extensively examined by Paul Krugman [10]

References